ECONOMYNEXT – Sri Lanka is heading into uncertain territory with an obsession on interest rates, a trigger happy central bank which tends to deliver liquidity shocks through open market operations, which now buys bonds to create money, and the budgets deteriorating on top of all that.
In 2018 the central bank triggered two runs on the currency with a combination of a buffer strategy (where maturing bonds were repaid with a central bank re-financed overdrafts), overnight and term reverse repo injections and rupee/dollar swaps of a type used by hedge funds to generate domestic currency to hit currency pegs.
If the central bank generated currency crises through open market operations in 2018 when budgets were tight, and there was a fuel price formula, what are the odds on it keeping the exchange rate steady when budgets deteriorate?
There have been claims made that in 2005, Sri Lanka had similar economic troubles, but the country managed to overcome them, despite a war.
But many countries which had no war had been brought down by money printing central banks and soft pegs of the type Sri Lanka has now, when private credit picks up and budget deficits widen.
Countries like Argentina, Ecuador, Mexico, Turkey had been repeatedly brought down by similar central banks.
Then
2020 is not 2005 for several reasons. The 2002 to 2004 United National Party administration fixed many of the problems with the economy that came with the peg collapse in 1999/2000.
The currency was, actually, appreciating in 2004, bad loans were coming down, inflation was near zero when the ministries were taken over by Chandrika Kumaratunga in the last quarter of 2003, triggering a run on the rupee.
Most of the ‘circular debt’ in Petroleum and Ceylon Electricity Board and the banks were cleared. Tight fiscal policies and moderate state expenditure, wage restraints and a hiring freeze, allowed the private sector to expand.
Several agencies were privatised, which brought an immediate transformation of the economy. The administration followed clear classical economic policies the central bank under A S Jayewardene was for sound money.
Now
But the last UNP administration followed loosely socialist policies based on price controls, taxing private citizens and companies to give high salaries to state workers, under an International Monetary Fund program of ‘revenue based fiscal consolidation’ with a highly unstable peg. (What went wrong; Sri Lanka’s illiberal economics and unsound money : Bellwether)
CPC was heavily mis-managed despite a price formula by restricting its ability to buy foreign exchange and forcing it to borrow dollars, despite having cash surpluses, based on Mercantilist false doctrine. This strategy – pioneered by Mercantilists many years ago – will continue to harm the country into the future. (Nick Leeson-style losses at Sri Lanka’s CPC raise big questions)
The central bank also followed un-interrupted Mercantilist monetary policy, targeting the real effective exchange rate (an external anchor) along with other domestic anchors, while the IMF stayed silent and/or added fuel to the fire with different types of ‘overvaluation’ calculations. (Sri Lanka may be heading for a triple anchor, ‘inflation targeting’ oxymoron: Bellwether)
The central bank based on public pronouncements also targeted core inflation, and under an IMF program, a high headline inflation of eight percent (domestic anchors) which gave enough rope to the monetary authority to generate balance of payments troubles. ((Sri Lanka needs a narrower inflation target to stop stagflation, BOP crises: Bellwether)
The IMF also taught the central bank to target an output gap, essentially a variation of so-called full employment policies that led to the collapse of the US dollar, and the Bretton Woods system itself.
Similar full employment policies also led to the Sterling Crises and made the UK a shadow of its former self. It also made the Bank of England a client of the IMF.
Collapsing exchange rates pushed up nominal interest rates to high levels in both the US and the UK and triggered stagflation.
As predicted, the UNP administration paid the price for REER targeting and currency depreciation and the monetary indiscipline of the central bank in the electorate.
You may also read
Sri Lanka’s UNP pays the price for currency depreciation, REER targeting: Bellwether
Sri Lanka’s path to debt and destruction paved by currency collapse, REER targeting: Bellwether
Monetary Mess
After generating structurally high interest rates with monetary instability and dual anchor conflicts Sri Lanka’s central bank also slapped price controls, on lending and deposits of banks, invoking a blunt instrument it had not used before.
“The Monetary Law also seeks to give the Central Bank of Ceylon, powers of control over the direction as well as over the quantity of bank finance in Ceylon,” an analyst wrote in the 1951 August issue of The Banker Magazine in London as Sri Lanka’s money printing central bank was established.
“Although this is intended primarily as an anti-inflation regulation it is obvious that it can be used to slow down or prevent the increase of any particular type of credit which the Monetary Board regards as undesirable,” the Banker Magazine warned.
The central bank could slap portfolio ceilings, prescribe minimum capital and minimum cash margins as cover for any letters of credit they open.
“One other control granted to the central bank, that of limiting the interest paid by commercial banks on deposits or changes on loans, is apparently intended to be used only sparingly,” The Banker noted.
“It will be obvious from this summary that the new Monetary Board is going to be given almost unlimited power of control over the banking system of Ceylon, – a power which, if misused could do irreparable harm to the island’s economy.”
In Sri Lanka and elsewhere deposit rates do not fall quickly after a ‘flexible exchange rate’ collapse partly due to competition and also because bad loans squeeze inflows to banks.
By trying to resist market rates, the central bank had denied resources to banks to lend in the recovery period. A strengthening exchange rate, after an initial fall in consumption, would have led to a V-shaped recovery.
In another severe deterioration of policy under Governor Indrajit Coomaraswamy, the central bank had broken the rule on only buying Treasury bills and has started buying bonds.
By breaking the restraints, Governor Coomaraswamy had opened the doors for the central bank to manipulate rates far down into the yield curve and undermine stability.
As a basic principle, a central bank should sell long term sterilisation securities and build up reserves when private credit is weak, and rates are low, not buy them. Later, at the top of the credit cycle if necessary short term securities can be sold when they come up for maturity.
Either way to keep the peg and preserves reserves, all sterilisation securities have to be rolled over, preferably to the same buyer.
IMF Adds to Instability
In addition to powers contained in the monetary law, that allows the central bank to control rates and generate instability, the IMF program now in force, itself intensified the problems.
One was the lack of a ceiling on domestic assets of the central bank, which would have put the central bank’s domestic operations in a straight jacket immediately and provided stability to the currency, the country, the people and energy prices.
The disorderly market condition rule, to defend the rupee (delaying interventions to stop the fall of the rupee from excess liquidity until the currency fell sharply), further undermined the credibility of the rupee and generated panic.
In Pakistan, specific ceiling were set on domestic assets of the central bank.
The State Bank of Pakistan was banned from sterilising interventions with new money, unlike Sri Lanka’s program, which left everything open-ended with an upper-level inflation target big enough to sink Sri Lanka.
“Going forward, the SBP might intervene to prevent a possible overshooting or disorderly market conditions (DMCs), while at the same time not suppressing an underlying trend and in a manner consistent with rebuilding reserves,” the IMF program in Pakistan read.
“These sales will not be sterilised, such that the stance of monetary policy will be correspondingly tightened if intervention is needed.”
Though Pakistan programs (and Argentina’s), which through the sterilisation block, tries to prevent the central bank from targeting a call money/overnight rate with liquidity injections, nevertheless has a ‘disorderly’ undertaking that triggers panic in forex markets.
The DMC is downwardly skewed.
While selling dollars is delayed, which can trigger panic in forex markets, there is no corresponding DMC before buying dollars, giving rise to convertibility undertakings which are skewed towards depreciation.
No Excess Demand from Deficits
There is a belief in Sri Lanka articulated by policymakers and central bankers in particular that budget deficits generate excess demand.
They don’t.
Deficits transfer money from savers and bond holders into government spending.
Excess demand comes if the central bank prints money by purchasing bonds or through open market operations to accommodate the deficit.
“No additions to the money supply take place when the savings of the people are claimed by the government to finance its outlays; such operations merely shift moneys from the pockets of the savers into the pockets of the recipients of government disbursements,” explained B R Shenoy a classical economist who correctly identified the problems in the island and the solutions in Economic Situation and Trends in Ceylon – A Program of Reform as far back as 1966.
However if deficits are financed by the central bank it expands the money supply, creating excess demand.
“The same and result emerges when Public Debt is sold to commercial banks,” and are paid for by central bank money, he said.
This was seen in the ‘buffer strategy’ fiasco and term repo injections which generated instability in 2018.
In the final analysis there is not much difference whether cash injections are used for private credit by banks or the Treasury for the deficit. That is why in 2018, there was currency crises despite a very good budget
That budget deficits cause inflation was also an idea propagated by Arthur Burns around the time the US dollar and the Bretton Woods collapsed. Classical economists have pointed out that especially in 1973 and 1974 he went around spreading this idea.
To boost his argument he made deficits look larger by adding the borrowings of the Federal National Mortgage Association.
Deficits – if no money is printed – simply crowds out private investment or consumption. Currencies fall because deficits are accommodated by the central bank.
The cut in taxes if implemented in December could lead to Rs30 or 40 billion revenue loss a month. This is a considerable shock. But if it is accommodated by foreign borrowings, or through domestic borrowings at a higher interest rate, it may be possible to maintain stability.
However, December is a month where money is printed to accommodate festival demand. In January provisional advances are given, and salary hikes of state workers take effect.
If rates are controlled through liquidity injections, and the DMC is deployed, the grounds will be set for instability and capital flight.
In 1994, A S Jayewardene as central bank Governor, who was an LSE graduate, inherited an awful budget from the UNP election promises.
The budget deficit was 10.5 percent of GDP in 1994 and 10.1 percent of GDP in 1995. He was able to weather the shock with high call money rates.
Now deficits are much lower though there are doubts about the size of the GDP itself.
It must be borne in mind that Argentina frequently collapses because of the BCRA, not the budget. It was very clearly evident in the latest crisis.
Before the latest currency collapse, the central government deficit was a little over 5 percent, and the overall public sector deficit was over 6 percent.
When a deficit deteriorates by one percent the central bank resists rate hike with injections, and all hell breaks loose.
Argentina’s foreign debt was only 37 percent in 2017. Then foreign debt ballooned to nearly 52 percent of GDP as the BCRA printed money, and the peso collapsed.
John Exter, in fact, is said to have used one of the provisions in Sri Lanka’s central bank which is credited with being invented by Raúl Prebisch, who helped design the BCRA and started the beginning of the end of Argentina.
The Confluence of Factors
Sri Lanka is now seeing the confluence of three deadly monetary regressions, with the restraints set by A S Jayewardene also being casually broken by Governor Coomaraswamy.
The first is the ‘flexible exchange rate’ involving call money rate targeting with excess liquidity which removes the protection the rupee gets from the policy corridor. The one-sided ‘DMC’ convertibility undertaking with the foreign reserve target is the second.
The third is the newly given license to repress of the long term bond yield curve with central bank bond purchases.
To this monetary witches’ brew has now been added a spiking fiscal deficit with the possibility of a boost in consumption and private credit.
Usually ‘stimulus’ packages are temporary, which will expire when private credit and consumption picks up. Capital spending projects stop when the projects end. Tax cuts expire. But we know of no such limits.
This column is based on ‘The Price Signal by Bellwether‘ published in the December 2019 issue of the Echelon Magazine. To read Bellwether columns as soon as they are published, subscribe to Echelon Magazine at this link. The i-tunes app can be downloaded from here.
Do you advocating higher interest rates, when budget deficit is high? Although there is room to conduct loose Monetary policy? . We would like to know your thoughts on how the economy could stimulate , without doing any fiscal or monetary stimulus???